overview
beginnings
competition
ISPs
hosting
agencies
regulation
backbone
periphery
numbering
demand
supply
futures
CIIP
crimes
policing
crises
statistics
landmarks 1
landmarks 2

related
Guides:
Networks
& GII
Economy

related
Profiles:
the net in
Australia
communication
revolutions
auDA
dot-NZ
Telco
Boom &
Bust
Telco
Privatisation
|
regulation and policy direction
This page looks at regulation of Australian telecommunications
as of August 2003.
It covers -
In
essence, regulation of telecommunications in Australia
has three aspects: technical regulation (eg standards),
rules about how the network is used (affecting for example
copyright and censorship), and competition regulation
(reflecting the dominant position of the five largest
telecommunication groups). The 'co-regulatory' regime
provides for substantial self-regulation by industry,
both through formal codes and through administration of
particular matters (including disputes) by industry bodies.
legal framework
Section 51(v) of the Australian Constitution establishes
telecommunications (including broadcasting) as a Commonwealth
- ie national - power.
Subject to section 92 of the Constitution the Commonwealth
is able to make laws with respect to telecommunications.
That power embraces legislation such as
- the
Telecommunications Act 1997 (here),
the Broadcasting Services Act 1992 (here),
which regulates television and radio broadcasting,
-
the Broadcasting Services Amendment (Online
Services) Act 1999 (BSA
Act) - discussed here
- which provides the basis for federal regulation of
online content
-
Crimes Legislation Amendment (Telecommunications
Offences and Other Measures) Act 2004.
The
legal framework for Australian telecommunications regulation
involves a broad range of legislation, some concerned
specifically with market activity within the telecommunications
industry, some with content regulation (eg censorship,
security and copyright)
and some with general trade practices/competition questions.
Responsibility for that legislation involves several federal
ministers and their subordinate departments and agencies.
The legislation establishes a "co-regulatory regime",
with substantial self-regulation by telecommunication
service providers. That industry self-regulation is encouraged
through the development of voluntary industry codes of
practice and technical standards, fostered in particular
by the Australian Communications Industry Forum (ACIF).
The expectation is that self-regulation will encourage
industry to respond to customer needs without first having
to overcome excessive regulatory restrictions.
Cogent analysis of the regime is provided in Australian
Telecommunications Regulation (Uni of NSW: UNSW Press
2004) edited by Alasdair Grant and Wrong Number: Australia's
Telecommunications Mess and How to Fix It (Crows
Nest: Allen & Unwin 2008) by Henry Ergas.
policy direction
As noted on preceding pages of this profile, policy direction
reflects a broad consensus characterised by -
- arguments
that competition within the telecommunication sector
produces public goods (eg lower prices for consumers,
greater availability of infrastructure, scope for business
users to spread risk)
- a
substantial degree of industry self-regulation as not
only politically and economical desirable but technically
essential, since government agencies are not equipped
to address some technical concerns
- a
differentiation between technical regulation (eg network
standards) and competition regulation (attention to
anticompetitive behaviour, particularly by dominant
players), with the latter forming part of a broader
economy-wide competition policy
- reliance
on private sector investment in and management of networks,
in contrast to past shibboleths about public sector
ownership of the "commanding heights" of the
economy
- acceptance
that particular operators may be owned and controlled
by offshore interests, in contrast to restrictions on
ownership and control of broadcasters
- differentiation
of service standards, with notions of a basic voice
service (reflected in the Universal Service Obligation)
for all Australians and what are tacitly premium services
for which access is determined by geographical location
or preparedness to pay additional charges.
As preceding pages of this profile have suggested, there's
been less agreement on specific questions. Arguably the
1997 legislation - and implementation by bodies such as
the ACCC - was 'pro-competition' but inadequately 'pro-competitor',
favouring the incumbent operators.
Eli Noam's 'Entrepreneurship & Government in Telecommunications'
- in The Emergence of Entrepreneurship Policy
(Cambridge: Cambridge Uni Press 2003) edited by David
Hart - comments that "it is difficult to do competitive
telecommunications" -
the
costs of new networks were higher than expected, from
truck rolls to customer acquisition to capacity planning.
And the incumbents were not passively accepting their
challengers but instead fighting them through market
responses, foot-dragging and regulatory delay. They
were helped by the risk-averse attitudes of important
customers who wanted to be sure that the new network
providers would be round next month
before
noting incumbency advantages such as network externalities
and economies of scale.
next page
(backbone)
|
|