overview
experience
turnover
returns
creators
business
gatekeepers
curators
works
values
indexes
theft
insurance
finance
decay
to 1959
to 1984
to 2004
2005 -

related
Guides:
Economy
Capital &
Investment
Money
Taxation

related
Profiles:
Droit de
Suite
Dotcom
Bubble
Forgery
& Fraud
Repatriation
& Spoliation
Art
Investment
Funds
|
overview
This note considers circulation and pricing of cultural
commodities - old master paintings, sculpture, manuscripts,
prints, antiquities and other collectibles.
It covers -
- experience
- the psychology of collecting, status, corporate art
collections and galleries
- turnover
- how big is the art market and other collectibles markets?
- returns
- investment in collectibles such as fine art
- creators
- production and discovery of collectibles
- business
- dealers, auctioneers and regulators
- gatekeepers
or cheerleaders - questions about authentication, scholarship,
journalism and policing
- curators
- museums, libraries, galleries and other institutions
as custodians and creators of value
- works
- profiles of trade in particular works
- values
- valuation principles and practices
- indexes
- art sale indexes and other information sources
- theft
and other loss
- insurance
and finance
- to
1959 - landmarks in pricing of collectibles to 1959
- to
1984 - landmarks to 1984
- to
2004
- landmarks to 2004
- 2005
- and from 2005 onwards
It
supplements discussion elsewhere on this site regarding
Droit de Suite, the Dot-com Bubble, Forgery
and Indigenous Authenticity
Marks.
It also provides points of reference for the discussion
of domain name prices, hedge funds and private equity
funds.
orientation
The following pages consider circulation of cultural commodities,
in particular questions about prices and trade in the
fine arts.
Circulation is of interest because it offers insights
about -
- the
operation of markets, including the behavioural finance
evident in a succession of bubbles
and in speculative trading in domain
names
- disagreements
regarding rewards and risks for creators, consumers
and intermediaries, including debate about schemes such
as Droit de Suite and
about intellectual property as an incentive for production
or merely as a signal of the community's respect for
creativity
- the
shaping and exploitation of taxation
regimes, with Australia for example providing concessions
in capital gains tax (CGT) treatmment of art and offering
incentives for donation of particular commodities to
specific institutions
- the
subversion and cooption of gatekeepers and custodians,
with art museums for example being an integral part
of the market rather than entities operating in a different
sphere
- media
representations of elite and popular culture, capital,
innate value and investment opportunities
- changing
patterns in aesthetics and critical esteem: yesterday's
superstars (Alma-Tadema, Salvator Rosa) are often today's
dreck and tomorrow's rediscovery, today's pickled shark
with a million dollar price tag is tomorrow's shark
soup?
- contingencies
such as forgery, misrepresentation,
spoliation and restitution
- financial
mechanisms such as hedge
funds or private equity
funds (and difficulties facing specialist Art
Investment Funds).
frozen money?
Art can have a direct personal impact without any consideration
of context. One can for example be moved by a Rothko painting
or Shostakovich quartet without any awareness of the creator's
career. Appreciation of a Klimt portrait or Pre-Columbian
ceramic is not dependent on any sense that they are postcards
from another world, although understanding of the culture
in which an item originated and of the ways that it has
been viewed in the past may enrich a contemporary's experience.
Everyone reading this page, for better or worse, lives
in societies where people are accustomed to assign monetary
values to objects and to intangibles. Quantification remains
the rage, whether that's in terms of 'best seller' and
'top ten lists, risk analysis in health systems, the "most
expensive" painting (or teddy bear), or econometric
studies purporting to show that dying young after a burst
of creativity is a good career move for both visual artists
and James Dean epigones.
It is unsurprising, then, that many people conceptualise
cultural commodities in terms of dollars: how much the
item cost, how much the owner would receive if the item
was sold, which items are increasing in price, which are
increasing at a faster rate than others. That conceptualisation
is underpinned by tax regimes and by scholars and curatorial
institutions. Prices matter and in practice many cultural
commodities are frozen money.
Some items are expensive because of 'innate'
attributes, for example the precious metals and other
material used in their construction or because they embody
particular aesthetic values. Those values may or may not
prove durable over time and a sceptic might argue that
some leading art works are essentially famous for being
famous.
Some items are expensive because of association:
the tureen used by Marie Antoinette (more so than that
used by Maria Theresa), the letter from George Washington
or Michael Jackson, props from Gone With The Wind,
the upright piano used by John Lennon (US$2.08m).
Some are expensive because they are rare,
either because they are unique productions (eg a painting)
or because formerly abundant supplies have been winnowed
by time. Some stamps and coins, for example, fetch million
dollars prices merely because only one or two examples
are extant.
Rarity presupposes authenticity. As noted
elsewhere on this site some societies are more concerned
than others to privilege originality in creation of works
and transmission of an authentic 'original', a transmission
that often means that the original is more bruised than
a fine contemporary copy.
Those attributes reinforce perceptions of value, with
a spectrum of collectors competing for 'desirable' items
and markets catering for the circulation of such items.
Such markets often feature speculative buying, with for
example individuals and other entities purchasing items
in the expectation that prices will increase sufficiently
to provide that buyer with a substantial profit when the
item is sold.
That expectation reflects a recognition that supplies
of some items are finite (eg most of the output of particular
artists has disappeared over the past 300 years and much
of the remaining work has been absorbed by art museums).
It also reflects belief that demand will continue, even
increase in future. Such belief is often rational, given
the rarity of aesthetic revolutions and the conservativism
of scholars and curatorial institutions (which tend to
relegate works to their basements when fashion changes
rather than unloading them onto the market).
Prices rise and fall. Fluctuation in what is paid for
items - and for broader esteem given to genres, schools
and individual artists - reflects factors such as changing
fashions in what is 'great art' (or merely what is currently
underappreciated and thus an investment opportunity),
marketing by intermediaries, interest rates and emulation
of peers. Peaks in the prices highlighted in the final
pages of this note thus reflect factors such as
- competition
among JP Morgan and his peers at the turn of last century
for canvases by Old Masters (and for now forgotten treats
such as maiolica and boulle)
- low
interest rates, permissive lending by financiers and
expectations that good times will continue to roll during
booms since the 1939-45 War (for example the US in the
mid 1960s and 1980s, Japan in the 1980s property bubble)
appreciation and investment
The following pages indicate that some lucky or sagacious
people have enjoyed substantial gains through appreciation
in the market value of art works over the past century.
The same figures, however, also illustrate declines in
value - whether in nominal or real terms. Some belle epoque
masters have yet to regain the prices achieved during
the 1880s; paintings by Alma-Tadema and his contemporaries
for many years were an embarrassment rather an embodiment
of a million dollars.
William Baumol's landmark 1986 'Unnatural Value: Or Art
as a Floating Crap Game' in the American Economic
Review compared the prices of 500 paintings sold
more than once over a 410 year period (1652 to 1961),
concluding that when inflation is considered fine art
returned a mere 0.55% per annum.
Subsequent research by Mei & Moses indicated that
over the past 50 years fine art provided an average annual
return after inflation of 8.2%, somewhat less than the
8.9% annualised return of the Standard & Poor's 500
Stock Index. A Guercino, Klimt, Kokoschka or even a Warhol
is of course a much more pleasing wall decoration than
a share of IBM, Bond Corporation or BHP.
John Picard Stein's 1977 'The Monetary Appreciation of
Paintings' in 85(5) Journal of Political Economy
1021-1036 offered an even bleaker view for economic rationalists,
arguing that on average, fine art provides a net return
for durable services (less insurance and maintenance costs,
adjusted for tax and liquidity considerations) of 1.6%.
Limited supply (eg as Old Masters increasingly migrate
from private hands to institutional collections) and the
canonical status of particular artists/schools means that
some works have exprerienced less volatility than others.
William Goetzmann thus demonstrated that during the post-1990
art market slump Old Masters suffered less (down by 16%)
than contemporary (down 40%) and Impressionist (down 51%)
works.
That is consistent with observations in The Worth
of Art: Pricing the Priceless (New York: Assouline
2001) by Judith Benhamou-Huet, Talking Prices: Symbolic
Meanings of Prices on the Market for Contemporary Art
(Princeton: Princeton Uni Press 2005) by Olav Velthuis
and 'The monetary appreciation of paintings: from realism
to Magritte' by Luc Renneboog & Tom Van Houtte in
26(3) Cambridge Journal of Economics (2002) 331-358.
The latter concludes that
art
investments underperform equity market investments owing
to the high risk of investing in art and its high transaction
costs, resale rights and insurance premia. In addition,
the Markowitz efficient frontier shows limited diversification
potential for art.
next page (the
experience of collecting)
|
|