overview
impacts
byte tax
Australia
global
taxonomies
income
corporate
VAT
production
compliance
landmarks

related
Guides:
Governance
Information
Economy
e-Publishing

related
Profiles:
Email, SMS
& Chat
|
the byte tax
This
page looks at proposals for a 'byte' tax, 'bit tax' or
'email tax'.
It covers -
the proposals
Those taxes would essentially involve a charge (by
a national government or, in some of the more problematical
proposals, by the United Nations through a new or existing
body such as the ITU) on
traffic over the internet.
Internet service providers and telecom carriers would
collect -
- a
flat user fee, or
- a
charge per specific number of email
messages (eg a cent per message or per 100 messages),
or
- a
charge per SMS message, or
- a
charge by the quantity of information sent/received
(eg for internet telephony and video), or even
- a
charge by the value of information/sent received (eg
entertainment content would be charged at a higher rate
than email).
What
would be charged, who would be charged (consumers in the
first world but not in the third?), how the tax would
be collected and how it would be spent depends on which
proposal you are considering.
Broadly, proponents argue that such a tax will offset
the erosion of traditional revenue collection as we all
go online or that it is a new, low-impact tax that can
be used for international development. Revenue would rise
and fall in direct proportion to use of information &
communication technologies (ICT) and in the cost of ICT
related employment.
Critics argue that such taxes are regressive (ie disproportionately
affect the poor), will not work without total international
cooperation, will primarily benefit unresponsive global
bodies - the UN, World Bank and Bank for International
Settlements are among the usual suspects - and that the
technology for administration does not exist or remains
too expensive.
Subhajit Basu's 2004 To Tax or Not to Tax? That is
the question? Overview of Options in Consumption Taxation
of E-Commerce paper
commented that
A
distinguishing characteristic of the bit tax is that
the entire burden of collecting and remitting the tax
is borne by the carrier company. It can be argued that
carrier companies possess the necessary technical and
labour resources to effectively perform such a function.
But, who, in the final analysis, will shoulder the bulk
of the tax burden or incidence? Will carrier companies
absorb the cost, or will they pass it onto consumers?
If carriers choose to pass the costs onto consumers
(a reasonable assumption it appears), will they do so
in a non-neutral manner because carriers lack the means
to accurately separate e-commerce from non-e-commerce
data flows? With a bit tax, there could also be problems
with enforcing compliance on the part of carrier companies.
Without a central international regulatory agency to
oversee the carriers, there would be difficulties in
ensuring that companies collect the correct amount of
tax and accurately allocate the funds to the designated
governments.
More
problematically, he comments that a bit tax fails a basic
principle of taxation because
it
would discourage electronic transmission of information.
Economic resources would be wasted through efforts to
minimize the 'bit tax'. Further, it would also be counterproductive
in that it burdens e-commerce and its productivity.
For example, software companies might continue to ship
magnetic tapes and cartridges rather than use the more
efficient method of transmitting the data electronically.
the EU report
Although there is disagreement, the first major proposal
for taxing electronic information was by Arthur Cordell
in a 1994 Club of Rome report. It was further developed
in a number of papers by Cordell and Ran Ide in 1995.
In Europe, the 1996 HLEG Policy Report (pdf)
of the High Level Expert Group on the Social Aspects of
the Information Society, chaired by Belgian economist
Luc Soete, argued that the growth of electronic commerce
- particularly on a cross-border basis - was seriously
eroding existing tax regimes.
The report called for research into alternative revenue
collection mechanisms, including a tax on every byte sent
over the net. Proponents argued that a tax at a very low
level per byte would be accepted by users yet would replace
part of the VAT (GST) and other revenue lost to ecommerce.
In 1994 a figure of around 1 cent per megabit was proposed.
That was said to be "very low" but has since
been criticised as out of kilter with broadband developments
(eg one Canadian estimate claims for video on demand the
tax is equivalent to 2 cents per second or C$72 per hour
and for speech over C$4 per hour).
The HLEG recommendations were rejected by the European
Commission. The 1998 Ottawa OECD conference on e-commerce
resulted in government endorsement of arguments in the
Electronic Commerce: Taxation Framework report
that existing taxation principles should apply to e-commerce
(eg no 'byte taxes').
1999 UN Report
In 1999 the Globalization With A Human Face (Raworth
Report) report
commissioned by the United Nations Development Programme
included proposals for a byte tax, along with a wide-ranging
review of intellectual property rights aspects of the
World Trade Organization, such as the TRIPS agreement
discussed in our intellectual property guide.
Revenue would be used by the UN in developing lower-income
areas within nations such as the US and Australia and
in addressing global development needs.
The proposal reflected suggestions by Nobel Prize economist
James Tobin
(1918-2002) for what's become known as the 'Tobin Tax',
a user fee/gross receipts tax on international capital
flows - with revenue being used to address north-south
or other 'divide' issues.
Tobin argued that a global 0.5% tax on foreign exchange
trading would generate revenue of US$1,500 billion (as
of 1992), while significantly reducing volatility. A 1995
report for the UN by D'Orville & Najman claimed that
a 0.1% tax would bring in US$56.4 billion. Other estimates
range from between US$50 billion to 250 billion per year,
based on tax rates of between 0.05% and 0.25%. (As a frame
of reference, official aid from 21 OECD countries to developing
countries in 2000 amounted to US$53.7 billion and the
Bank for International Settlements estimated global daily
foreign exchange turnover at US$1,490bn in 1998.)
There is a valuable critique of such claims in The
Tobin Tax - Coping With Financial Volatility (New
York: Oxford Uni Press 1996) edited by Mahbub ul Haq &
Inge Kaul. For a more positive view see Global Finance:
New Thinking on Regulating Speculative Capital Markets
(London: Zed Books 2000) edited by Walden Bello, Nicola
Bullard & Kamal Malhotra. A perspective is provided
by Ruben Lee's What Is An Exchange: The Automation,
Management & Regulation of Financial Markets
(Oxford: Oxford Uni Press 2000).
The Raworth report proposed a tax of the equivalent of
one US cent on every 100 emails sent by an individual.
The authors claimed that such a tax would have generated
US$70 billion in 1996, more than total official development
assistance that year, although user costs would be negligible.
Given soaring growth in email, global revenue would now
be significantly higher; it is estimated that in Belgium
in 1998 the tax would have yielded US$10 billion.
All well and good, but the report conceded that the UN
was not in a position to enforce the tax.
The report also referred to proposals for a 'digital tariff'
on transmissions, reflecting disparities in global internet
traffic (eg the US is a net exporter) and ongoing discussion
at the World Trade Organization.
In May 1998 the World Trade Organization's (WTO) 132 member
states announced that they "will continue their current
practice of not imposing customs duties on electronic
transmissions".
As one might expect, the report was widely criticised
as unviable: administratively impractical, politically
unrealistic. It has, however, been recurrently cited.
Discussions at the December 2003 World Summit on the Information
Society (WSIS)
for example featured suggestions that the ITU might somehow
assume responsibility for a tax that would fund third
world telecommunication infrastructure initiatives that
had failed to secure substantial support from either the
UN or major governments such as the US, France, Germany
and Japan.
state of play
The EU has, in effect, officially backed away from a byte
tax to fund international aid initiatives but in 2006
flirted with the idea of a tax to fund European Commission
operations, reflecting estimates that West Europeans spent
around US$19 billion sending 157 billion SMS
messages in 2005.
French MEP Alain Lamassoure for example gained international
media attention over a proposal for a €0.015 tax
on SMS messages and a €0.0001 tax on each email
sent. He commented that
This
is peanuts, but given the billions of transactions every
day, this could still raise an immense income.
The WTO 'Stand-still Agreement' remains in place.
As noted earlier in this guide, in the US the federal
Advisory Commission on Electronic Commerce (ACEC)
and other bodies have been holding hearings on internet-related
tax proposals. Don't hold your breath for coherent,
practical outcomes. The March 2000 round of consultations
mainly demonstrated disagreement within the federal government,
between individual states and within business groups.
Bricks-&-mortar retailers, including the International
Council of Shopping Centers and International Mass Retail
Association, have formed the E-Fairness
Coalition, a lobby group advocating a 'level playing
field' at the state and national levels. The Internet
Tax Fairness Coalition (ITFC)
is another lobby group.
The 1998 Ottawa OECD conference on ecommerce resulted
in government endorsement of the Electronic Commerce:
Taxation Framework report
that argued that existing taxation principles should apply
to e-commerce (eg no 'byte taxes'), there should be no
discriminatory taxation, consistent standards for cross-border
taxation should be developed, consumption taxes should
be imposed at the place of consumption, and digitised
products should not be regarded as goods for consumption
tax purposes.
other approaches
There are recurrent proposals from various sectors
for a content or recording tax, variously a levy on recordable
media (blank CDs, Zip disks, USB thumb drives and floppy
disks) or devices (computers, PVRs)
as part of a national, regional or global intellectual
property regime.
A model is the US Audio Home Recording Act 1992,
using a tax on DAT recorders and blank DAT media to fund
royalties to authors, performers and publishers. There
is similar legislation in some EU states and in Canada
(with an 'mp3 tax' in place from 2003), highlighted elsewhere
on this site.
In November 2005 the African ISP Association (AfrISPA)
invited all ISP associations at the Tunis WSIS
meeting to discuss establishment of a World ISP Association,
indicating that
The
main goal of the Association is to negotiate with the
Entertainment industry and to get the Entertainment
industry to fund the deployment of broadband around
the world.
The
"Entertainment industry" - and ISPs in advanced
economies - have yet to express much enthusiasm for that
notion.
next page (Australia)
|
|