title for Boom profile
home | about | site use | resources | publications | timeline   spacer graphic   Ketupa


overview

orientation

tulips

steam age

jazz & plastic

property

fleece

inflections

snapshot

dotcoms

telcos

peaks

au bubble

actors

media

fiction

accounting

regulators

clean-ups

bubble 2.0?

sinobubble

subprime

landmarks









related pages icon
related
Guides:


Economy

Governance

Networks

eCapital






related pages icon
related
Profiles:


Rail

Broadcast

section heading icon     tulips

This page offers context by considering some past booms, bubbles and crashes.

It covers -

subsection heading icon     introduction

The pre-1840s bubbles have been criticised as festivals of excess that left nothing behind except tears, bad law and anecdotes - in contrast to the railway bubbles that littered European and North American landscapes with rolling stock, telegraph lines and railway cuttings, much subsequently put to good use.

subsection heading icon     tulip time

Dutch 'Tulipmania' has attracted attention as the classic example of speculative excess, with absurd prices paid for derivatives and a consequent crash that supposedly devastated a flourishing economy.

Clarence Mackay's much-quoted but very impressionistic 1841 Extraordinary Popular Delusions & the Madness of Crowds claimed that

In 1634 the rage among the Dutch to possess tulip bulbs was so great that the ordinary industry of the country was neglected ... the population, even to its lowest dregs, embarked in the tulip trade

so that by early 1637 one bulb was reportedly sold for 6,700 guilders.

That was supposedly forty times greater than the average income and equivalent to the price of "a house on Amsterdam's smartest canal, including coach and garden". Mackay attributed the economic and political decline of the Netherlands to tulipmania.

In reality the situation was more complicated. Many people did not participate in the speculation, others did some momentarily and on a small scale. The Dutch Republic was not shattered by the crash: it survived and for some time surpassed its peers in terms of technological and economic development.

Peter Garber's crisp Famous First Bubbles: The Fundamentals of Early Manias (Cambridge: MIT Press 2000) and Anne Goldgar's Tulipmania: Money, Honor, and Knowledge in the Dutch Golden Age (Chicago: Uni of Chicago Press 2007) are useful correctives to some of the more lurid accounts, including Simon Schama's The Embarrassment of Riches: An Interpretation of Dutch Culture in the Golden Age of Riches (London: Routledge 1987), Mike Dash's Tulipmania (London: Gollancz 1999), Anna Pavord's The Tulip (London: Cape 1999) and Trevor Syke's engaging 2003 Tulips From Amsterdam (PDF).

Garber's work has been extended in Earl Thompson & Jonathan Treussard's 2002 The Tulipmania: Fact or Artifact? (PDF).

For an earlier panic see Reinhold Mueller's The Venetian Money Market: Banks, Panics, and the Public Debt (Baltimore: John Hopkins Uni Press 1997).

subsection heading icon     the Mississippi System

Financier John Law's Mississippi System has been characterised as "the greatest economic experiment prior to the Russian revolution of 1917". Unfortunately it was an experiment that went wrong.

Law's Mississippi Company merged with the Louisiana Company, which laid claim to one-third of what later became the US.

A single corporate entity thus encompassed ownership of the national debt and revenues from the state monopoly on tobacco and other substances, operation of what served as the French central bank, and expectations about development in the land of opportunity.

subsection heading icon     the South Sea bubble

The origins of the UK South Sea Bubble date from 1698, when the East India Company - an entity that generated meaningful revenue and formed the basis of Britain's empire in India - was persuaded to lend the government some £2m at a rate of 8% (the standard rate for government borrowing was 14%) in return for an extension of trading privileges.

The South Sea Company was established in 1711 to exploit a monopoly of British trade with South America and the Pacific Islands, expected to be lucrative once war with Spain finished. the Company's operation was deeply politicised, with opposition from factions associated with the Bank of England (at that time a private rather than public sector body).

The Treaty of Asiento effectively ended the war in 1713, with mixed effects for the South Sea Company. News of the treaty raised expectations and boosted share prices but the agreement in fact reduced the company's trading opportunities because it confirmed Spain's dominion over much of Latin America. (The Pacific Islands, contrary to claims of beaches rich in gold dust and diamonds, produced no revenue.)

The Company was thus reliant on development of the slave trade (shipping labour from Africa to Latin America), interest on the loan to the government and trade with the Spain's colonies. Its first trade voyage to the South Seas did not take place until 1717, just in time for major friction between Britain and Spain. The Company's promoters hyped its prospects, reflected in advancing £2 million to the government in 1717.

Two years later the Company offered to further take over financing the national debt. The government agreed, amid criticisms such that of Daniel Defoe in The Anatomy of Exchange-Alley (1719), which alleged stock manipulations -

Tis a compleat system of knavery; that 'tis a trade founded in fraud, born of deceit, and nourished by trick, cheat, wheedle, forgeries, falsehoods, and all sorts of delusions.

Through incompetence or corruption the Company's directors talked up the price of their shares, fuelling a speculative bubble that featured claims about the discovery of new technologies (including perpetual motion machines). In January 1720 the price of a share of South Sea stock was £128, climbing to £175 in February, £330 in March and £550 in May. It soared to £1,050 in June amid wild tales of South Sea riches and forecasts that prices would continue to climb.

The collapse came in September, an event that ruined many speculators and financial institutions. Sir Isaac Newton sold his £7,000 of stock for a 100% profit but reentered the market at the top, losing £20,000 and lamenting "I can calculate the motions of the heavenly bodies but not the madness of people". George I lost £56,000. Bishop of Peterborough and historian White Kennett commented

Enthusiasm in different shapes returns often upon this poor nation; we have had religious enthusiasm, political enthusiasm, and this was merely secular enthusiasm.

The Bishop of Norwich more polemically wrote that the collapse was divine judgment on

the universal inclination of all ranks of men and women too to excessive gaming which led to the occasion of bringing such a curse and blast upon us, as never was felt before by this Nation; by which we have been all of a sudden strangely impoverished in the midst of plenty, our riches having made themselves wings, and flying away nobody knows whither, and more families and single persons have been undone and ruined than hardly ever were known to have been so, by the most tedious and lingering war.

In 1721 formal investigations exposed large-scale corruption and stupidity, with political infighting being reflected in the prosecution of government officials and business figures. The Company's cashier fled overseas with details of bribes to politicians. Director Francis Hawes, who had acquired a major art collection and two country estates using his profits, was initially allowed to keep only £31 from declared assets of over £40,000 (in fact lower than the real value of £165,587). Colleague James Fellowes retained £10,000 from a fortune of £243,000. Confiscated wealth of course went to the state, rather than to victims.

Chancellor of the Exchequer John Aislabie was initially expelled from Parliament and sent to the Tower of London after being found guilty of the "most notorious, dangerous and infamous corruption" but once passions died down - and 'sweeteners' were distributed' - was allowed to retire to his Studley Royal estate and retain all property acquired before he became Chancellor.

Perceptions of fraud were reflected in Swift's comment in Gulliver's Travels (1726) that the Lilliputians

look upon fraud as a greater crime than theft, and therefore seldom fail to punish it with death; for they allege that care and vigilance, with a very common understanding, may preserve a man's goods from thieves, but honesty has no defence against superior cunning; and since it is necessary that there should be a perpetual intercourse of buying and selling, and dealing upon credit, where fraud is permitted and connived at, or has no law to punish it, the honest dealer is always undone, and the knave gets the advantage.

The so-called Bubble Act of 1720 (not repealed until 1825) banned all joint-stock corporations without parliamentary or royal authority and is claimed to have stifled economic development for years. The company survived until 1750 and its annuities were traded until 1853.

subsection heading icon     studies

The UK South Sea Bubble and French Mississippi Company Bubble have both attracted academic and popular studies. These include John Carswell's The South Sea Bubble (London: Cresset 1960), Virginia Cowles' The Great Swindle: The Story of the South Sea Bubble (London: Collins 1960) and Malcolm Balen's A Very English Deceit: The Secret History of the South Sea Bubble and the First Great Financial Scandal (London: Fourth Estate 2003).

Larry Neal's superb The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in the Age of Reason (Cambridge: Cambridge Uni Press 1990) and PGM Dickson's The Financial Revolution in England: A Study in the Development of Public Credit 1688-1756 (London: Macmillan 1967) are strongly recommended. The three-volume Great Bubbles: Reactions to the South Sea Bubble, the Mississippi Scheme & the Tulip Mania Affair (London: Pickering & Chatto ) edited by Ross Emmett collects contemporary responses. For a more recent view see Richard Dale's The First Crash: Lessons from the South Sea Bubble (Princeton: Princeton Uni Press 2004).

The UK (and thereby its neighbours) have been affected by a succession of Latin American bubbles. One work of particular value is Frank Dawson's The First Latin American Debt Crisis: The City of London and the 1822-25 Loan Bubble (New Haven: Yale Uni Press 1990).




icon for link to next page    next page  (steam age bubbles)



this site
the web

Google

version of June 2008
© Bruce Arnold
caslon.com.au | caslon analytics