title for Boom profile
home | about | site use | resources | publications | timeline   spacer graphic   Ketupa


overview

orientation

tulips

steam age

jazz & plastic

property

fleece

inflections

snapshot

dotcoms

telcos

peaks

au bubble

actors

media

fiction

accounting

regulators

clean-ups

bubble 2.0?

sinobubble

subprime

landmarks








related pages icon
related
Guides:


Economy

Governance

Networks

eCapital






related pages icon
related
Profiles:


Rail

section heading icon     steam age

This page offers context by considering booms, bubbles and crashes in the steam age.

It covers -

subsection heading icon     overviews

It is a truism that although history does not repeat, it does rhyme. Contemporary critics - informed or otherwise - have often pointed to episodes of railway boom and bust as models for -

  • speculation
  • investment
  • infrastructure development
  • unexpected benefits from expansion of the internet.

One critic thus compared the dot-com crash of 2000 to the end of the UK "Railway Mania" of the 1840s, (characterised as "the greatest technobubble ever by many measures").

Both bubbles -

collapsed because of gross overinvestment based on foreseeably foolish overestimates of demand for the new technology. But post-crash, most of the public attention in both cases was devoted to the frauds that were uncovered (and which did play important roles in inflating those bubbles). The final collapse of the Railway Mania came when it was discovered that George Hudson, the "Railway King," the dominant figure in British railroad industry at that time, had been massaging financial reports for his lines and paying high dividends out of capital. The Internet bubble had the final nail driven into its coffin when Bernie Ebbers' WorldCom was discovered to have committed gigantic accounting fraud and went bankrupt.

A realist might argue that government and community attention to fraud and blatant incompetence usually comes after a disaster and is not specific to bubbles. There is money to be made in forensic analysis and public postmortems. Lamentations about the wickedness of the corrupt, the overweening ambition of corporate high-flyers (yesterday's Icarus, today's feather duster) and the vulgarity of conspicuous consumption - particularly by people who do not hold on to their loot - have a cathartic value.

Walter Bagehot's 1873 Lombard Street commented that -

The mercantile community will have been unusually fortunate if during the period of rising prices it has not made great mistakes. Such a period naturally excites the sanguine and the ardent; they fancy that the prosperity they see will last always, that it is only the beginning of a greater prosperity. They altogether over-estimate the demand for the article they deal in, or the work they do. They all in their degree—and the ablest and the cleverest the most—work much more than they should and trade far above their means. Every great crisis reveals the excessive speculations of many houses which no one before suspected, and which commonly indeed had not begun or had not carried very far those speculations, till they were tempted by the daily rising price and the surrounding fever

Other writers have pointed to railway-related financial crashes in the 1870s, 1890s or early 1900s as models for the dot-com crash, arguing that the early UK bubbles were unrepresentative.

It is questionable whether all the railway busts had a profound and long-lasting effect on national/regional economies (Britain, for example, appears to have recovered quite quickly, although the pain was shared unevenly), whether the busts were manifestations of broader economic changes rather than the causes of economic depressions, and whether the collapses had a lesser effect on a nation's overall economy and culture than for example the 'decline of the aristocracy' exacerbated by cheap grain from the Americas.

subsection heading icon     the UK railway booms

The first UK railway bubble followed an economic decline in the 1830s that was associated with cheap labour and materials and with low interest rates. That encouraged borrowing for the construction of lines (although many lines remained plans rather than actual infrastructure), particularly once early lines began paying 10% dividends, ie over four times the contemporary interest rate.

Between 1830 and 1850 around £193 million (an estimated 36% of UK GDP in 1850 and equivalent to roughly £9.7 billion in 2002 values) was invested in UK railways. Private and government investment in US, Austrian, French, German, Russian, Australian and other railways during that century was of a similar scale.

Individual networks involved significant capital and expertise; their assessment - as noted in profiles here and here - formed the basis of modern corporate analysis. The first stages of the UK Great Western Railway, under engineer Isambard Kingdom Brunel, for example cost over £6 million (up from an estimated £2.5 million), perhaps equivalent to £18 billion in terms of the same proportion of 2002 UK GDP.

Charles Dickens' 1846 Dombey & Son commented that

There were railway patterns in its drapers' shops and railway journals in the windows of its newsmen. There were railway hotels, office-houses, lodging houses, boarding houses; railway plans, maps, views, wrappers, bottles, sandwich boxes, and railway time-tables; railway hackney- coach and cab stands; railway omnibuses, railway streets and buildings, railway hangers-on and parasites, and flatterers out of all calculation. There was even railway time observed in clocks, as if the sun itself had given in.

The UK railway industry was marked by two manias in 1837 and 1845.

Only 970 miles had been sanctioned by Parliament prior to 1836, but 955 miles were approved in 1836 and a further 543 miles in 1837. Speculative investment - exacerbated by uncertain statistics and inexperience in forecasting traffic/revenue - interacted with entrepreneurs who sought to outbuild each other (or merely to build networks to particular locations while the opportunity was available) and who in some cases expected to make money by through fees for civil engineering rather than operating a line.

As a result some lines were not economical, some could not be completed because costs overran projections, much money was absorbed in promotional or regulatory costs and many schemes collapsed ingloriously. Market capitalisation of UK railways hit a peak in July 1845; by 1850 those shares were worth less than half the capital spent on them, some were worthless and the overall dividend rate had sunk to 2%.

Investors returned to the market because traffic and the revenue of surviving companies continued to grow (albeit more slowly than initially projected), because survivors were able to acquire assets at a discount and introduce economies of scale, and because broader growth of the economy meant that capital was available.

Herbert Spencer's 1854 Railway Morals & Railway Policy identified discrepancies between community perceptions of railway finances and actual activity. He charged, somewhat unfairly, that the public equated railways with financial malpractice

Associating the ideas of wealth and respectability, and habitually using respectability of synonymous with morality, it seems to them incredible that many of the large capitalists administration to administer railway affairs should be guilty indirectly enriching themselves in the expense of their constituents.

Although he cited instances of company boards maintaining corporate records in cypher, false share registers, gaps in corporate minutes and 'men of straw' holding large shares on behalf of directors - the extent of malpractice has been questioned or reaffirmed in several works.

They include A Arnold & S McCartney's 2001 Bricks Without Straw (PDF) and 'Financial reporting in the context of crisis: reconsidering the impact of the 'mania' on early railway accounting' in 11 European Accounting Review (2002) 401-417 and 'The railway mania of 1845-1847: Market irrationality or collusive swindle based on accounting distortions?' in 16(5) Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal (2003) 821-852, Malcolm Reed's Investment in Railways in Britain 1820-1844: a Study in the Development of the Capital Market (Oxford: Oxford Uni Press 1975), neomarxist 'Accounting for the 'railway mania' of 1845 - a great railway swindle?' by Rob Bryer in 16(5) Accounting, Organizations and Society (1991) 439-486, R W Kostal's Law & English Railway Capitalism 1825-1875 (Oxford: Oxford Uni Press 1994) and White-Collar Crime in Modern England - Financial Fraud and Business Morality, 1845-1929 (Cambridge: Cambridge Uni Press 2003) by George Robb.

By 1844 UK networks amounted to around 2,000 miles (linking London, Dover, Southampton, Brighton, Birmingham, Manchester, Leeds, Newcastle, Bristol and Exeter). After the first crash most operators were profitable, resulting in a second boom that saw 1,263 schemes (with capital of £1,123m) in the pipeline. The Manchester Guardian noted that during one week 89 new ventures (requiring capital of £84 million) had been advertised in three newspapers, with some 357 schemes advertised in those papers for an estimated £332 million.

Many of the proposals were unsuccessful and some lines were later acquired by the major operators at a discount of up to 93% but by 1853 total UK lines had increased to 7,000 miles, essentially the same network in place in 1965. Aggregate construction costs to 1870 are estimated at £250 million (relative to the UK GDP of £1bn per year in 1866). Gross revenues reached £5m pa in 1844 and tripled by 1852 (when freight overtook passengers for the first time), rising to £23m by 1870.

subsection heading icon     and in the US and Continent

Similar phenomena were experienced in France, in Germany and Austria (where the railway mania of the early 1870s ended with a short but particular sharp crisis in banking) and in the US, with a cycle of construction, stockmarket bubble and corporate rationalisation roughly every twenty years from the 1850s to 1913.

Thoreau complained in 1846 that

Men have an indistinct notion that if they keep up this activity of joint stocks and spades long enough all will at length ride somewhere, in next to no time, and for nothing; but though a crowd rushes to the depot, and the conductor shouts 'All aboard!' when the smoke is blown away and the vapor condensed, it will be perceived that a few are riding, but the rest are run over.

During the depression of 1859 US commentator Henry Carey Baird (1825-1912) complained that

our railroad system has cost more than $1,000,000 and has brought ruin upon nearly everyone connected with it, the nation included.

In 1860 the US had 30,000 miles of track. By 1914 that had increased to 253,000 miles and few critics agreed with Baird's assessment that a rail network was necessarily a bad bad thing.

Globalisation of financial pain became apparent in the 1870s, with problems spreading from Austria-Hungary (evident in the 'Wiener Krach' or 'Gründerkrach' of 1873) to Germany, France, the UK and US.

Industrial expansion, population growth and deregulation - especially in the mortgage sector - fostered growth of property-based lending in the late 1860s. A municipal and residential property boom in Paris, Vienna and London saw a spiral of construction, increased land values, borrowing and speculative development.

That was accompanied by state and private investment in railways and ports, some of which funnelled cheap grain, oilseed, timber and other commodities from the US and Russia. Imports of raw materials and of manufactured goods (reminiscent of imports from China in our epoch) affected - or were merely perceived as affecting - the economies of Central Europe, France, the Netherlands, Scandinavia and the UK. Those imports were often denounced as the 'American Invasion'.

The Vienna stock exchange crashed on 9 May 1873 ('Black Friday'), an event claimed by some observers to reflect recognition that Habsburg expectations about high levels of continued growth were overly optimistic and that property speculation had got out of hand. That crash saw the demise of banks, brokers and insurance companies across the continent (with the latter for example exposed as customers ceased paying premiums and the value of property diminished). UK banks husbanded their capital, wary that borrowers and institutions would fail.

That freeze in lending flowed through to the US, where the price of railway bonds had been in decline since 1871 amid European scepticism about corporate governance, the complexity of particular financial instruments and promises of a fixed return. That scepticism had seen railways and some suppliers resort to short-term bank loans to meet bond payments and maintain network development. In September 1873 railway czar Jay Cooke was unable to meet obligations, triggering a stock market crash and the 'Panic of 1873' that saw the demise of several hundred banks and large-scale unemployment.

Subsequent observers have hailed the US panic as beneficial, pointing to consolidation by well-managed (and well-capitalised) enterprises and lower transport costs that drove major growth in the Gilded Age of the following two decades. In Austria-Hungary the consequences of the Krach were more negative, with banks for example concentrating on lending to government rather than private industry during the following two decades.

subsection heading icon     studies

Charles Mackay's Extraordinary Popular Delusions and the Madness of Crowds, first published in 1841 (coinciding with the second UK Railway Bubble), frequently reprinted and available here, remains one of the more entertaining accounts of financial speculation. Mackay avoided analysis in favour of sensation and alas did not offer a contemprary view of rail speculation, instead repackaging accounts of tulipmania and pre-steam episodes of irrational exuberance.

Fans of Mackay might turn instead to Elias Canetti's quirky but penetrating Crowds & Power and more recent academic writing about behavioural finance noted above or to the persuasive revisionist study railway.com: Parallels between the early British railways and the ICT revolution (London: IEA 2003) by Robert Miller and 2003 paper by Andrew Odlyzko on The Many Paradoxes of Broadband. Odlyzko's site features a copy of John Palmer's 1959 bibliographic guide to the 19th century British railway press (PDF).

Context is provided by 'Writing about Finance in Victorian England: Disclosure and Secrecy in the Culture of Investment' by Mary Poovey in 45(1) Victorian Studies (2002) and Seymour Broadbridge's Studies in Railway Expansion 1825-1873 (London: Cass 1970).

Other work on the railway bubbles is highlighted in the more detailed discussion of railways as a precursor of the internet.

Those of particular significance include Alfred Chandler's Strategy & Structure: Chapters in the History of the Industrial Enterprise (Cambridge: MIT Press 1962), Railroads, the Nation's First Big Business (New York: Columbia Uni Press 1965) and Henry Varnum Poor - Business Editor, Analyst & Reformer (Cambridge: Harvard Uni Press 1956), Timothy Alborn's Conceiving Companies: Joint-Stock Politics in Victorian England (London: Routledge 1998), Robert Fogel's Railroads & American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Uni Press 1964) and Terence Gourvish's Railways & the British Economy 1830-1914 (London: Macmillan 1980).

For excitement in 1907 see The Panic of 1907 (New York: Wiley 2007) by Robert Bruner & Sean Carr




icon for link to next page    next page  (jazz & plastic)



this site
the web

Google

version of July 2007
© Bruce Arnold
caslon.com.au | caslon analytics